Inflation risks could trigger tight Fed policy

Kieran Davies

Coolabah Capital

A risk-management approach to unexpectedly high US inflation suggests that a fast return to neutral funds rate – 2½% on the Fed’s calculation or about 2% on market pricing – is prudent given the risk the Fed might need to adopt tight policy. A simple model shows that most of the recent sharp pick-up in inflation reflects pandemic disruptions, which extend to the labour market, where there has been an unprecedented reduction in the supply of labour. Inflation should ease as these disruptions abate later this year – which is consistent with market pricing of a broadly neutral policy rate and bias-adjusted measures of market inflation expectations – although the labour market should add slightly to inflation as unemployment falls below the NAIRU. Short-term inflation expectations have risen in line with actual inflation, but long-term measures remain anchored. If long-term expectations became unmoored, the Fed would need to react aggressively. In such a scenario, the slope of the yield curve would be the most reliable indicator of the risk of eventual recession.

Over the past year or so, several advanced economy central banks have started to unwind the emergency policy stimulus implemented at the height of the pandemic. Unconventional policy has often been adjusted first, with central banks either buying government bonds at a slower pace or stopping buying altogether. In the case of conventional monetary policy, some central banks have started to take back the emergency rate cuts of 2020. 

The Federal Reserve has signalled it will follow suit next month, stopping buying bonds and raising its policy rate for the first time since 2018. The Fed will update its forecasts at the March FOMC meeting, but the futures market is currently factoring in a series of hikes with the funds rate peaking at about 2% in 2023 before edging lower over 2024 and 2025 to 1¾%. 

This peak in interest rates is below the FOMC’s median estimate of a 2½% neutral funds rate, but within the 2-3% range of FOMC member estimates, also matching the NY Fed’s pre-pandemic model estimate of 2%.     

The catalyst for the earlier-than-anticipated rate rises has been the unexpectedly rapid acceleration in US inflation over the past year. For example, the Fed’s preferred measure of underlying inflation – the core PCE deflator – has increased by about 4½% over the past year, which is not only the highest inflation rate since the early 1980s, but the fastest core inflation among the large advanced economies. 

Market pricing of the funds rate returning to a broadly neutral level indicates that most investors believe this surge in inflation is temporary, easing as pandemic-driven disruptions fade, in line with Fed estimates of bias-adjusted market expectations of inflation. 

In this scenario, neutral policy would be consistent with the Fed achieving a “soft landing” for the economy, comprising broadly full employment and inflation returning to the Fed’s 2% target.  

Given the uncertainty around whether high inflation will continue, the prudent approach for the Fed would be to quickly increase the funds rate to a neutral level, placing it in a better position if it needs to adopt tight policy. 

Although the pandemic is very different to a usual economic cycle, history supports the view that taking out insurance by achieving a neutral funds rate would be the best course of action. That is, using the New York Fed’s model estimate of the neutral rate as a benchmark given its long history, the funds rate rarely spends much time at neutral and policy is often either loose or tight for extended periods. 

In fact, it is common for Fed tightening cycles to end in recession, sometimes by accident, but sometimes by design to rein in inflation. This is partly because a central bank confronted by high inflation has to be aggressive in raising rates in order to raise the real policy rate, while the Fed’s own research shows that inflation is not particularly sensitive to higher rates, with a 100bp increase in the funds rate reducing inflation by an estimated 0.35pp.  

The risk of tight monetary policy largely rests with whether high inflation becomes entrenched in the US. This most obvious way this could occur is if COVID-driven supply-side disruptions continue, such that producers and distribution chains are unable to keep up with the demand for goods. Another way is if the economy overheats and the unemployment rate falls below the NAIRU. Finally, high actual inflation could feed into high expected inflation, where long-term expectations anchor future inflation.

In order to judge these risks, we estimated a simple Phillips curve equation that specified:

  • Core PCE inflation = expected inflation + a*(unemployment rate – NAIRU) + supply factors

where:

  • Expected inflation = the Fed’s “index of common inflation expectations” (or CIE), which summarises the common trend across a large range of measures of expectations of households, firms, professional forecasters and investors;
  • NAIRU = the median FOMC estimate of the NAIRU; and
  • Supply factors = the New York Fed’s “global supply chain pressure index”, which distils information from global business surveys, shipping rates and air freight costs.

The model suggests that nearly all the acceleration in quarterly inflation over the past year reflects supply-chain problems, although the model cannot account for all the pick-up given it explains – a still‑respectable – 45% of the variation in inflation. A tighter labour market has also contributed slightly to higher inflation as the rapid decline in the unemployment rate has seen it become less of a drag on prices as it quickly approaches the NAIRU. Inflation expectations – anchored by relatively stable long-term expectations – have not had an appreciable effect on actual inflation.  

Inflation is likely to slow in the second half of this year as supply-side disruptions recede. There are already some indications that supply pressures have broadly peaked; for example, there has been a small decline in semiconductor prices and a partial rebound in vehicle production and sales, where a huge rise in motor vehicle prices has been the most prominent example of the impact of supply disruptions on inflation. 

However, the disruptions could take longer to abate than expected and may even intensify if another COVID variant emerges. This risk is underscored by the still-high world-wide number of deaths from COVID.  

And inflation pressures will be further amplified in the immediate term by the war between Russia and the Ukraine, and the striking impact of this event on, amongst other things, commodity and wheat prices.

With a massive monetary and fiscal stimulus greatly limiting the scarring of the labour market from the pandemic, the unemployment rate in the US fallen from a peak of 15% in 2020 – which was the second-highest level in modern history – to about 4%.  

This is a remarkable achievement, particularly when the unemployment rate often never regains its pre-recession level by the time the next recession rolls around and if it does it typically takes about four years. 

This means that the unemployment rate now broadly matches the FOMC’s median estimate of 4%, such that the labour market is no longer a drag on inflation. This has added slightly to inflation as the economy has recovered and should add more assuming that unemployment soon falls below 4%.    

Although the simple Phillips curve model relies on the gap between the unemployment rate and the NAIRU to capture the influence of the labour market on inflation, a rapid pick-up in wages growth raises the question of whether the gap is an adequate measure at present. For example, the Atlanta Fed’s measure of the median hourly wage is up almost 6% over the past year, which is the fastest wages growth since 2000. 

However, the acceleration in wages growth seems mostly driven by a substantial contraction in the supply of labour, where many workers who either lost their job or gave up looking for work during the pandemic have yet to return to the workforce. This is partly because government support during the pandemic did not retain the link between employers and stood-down staff, but also because many people are worried about the risk posed by COVID to them and their families. 

This supply shock has eased a little recently, but unless it is reversed it points to a large one-off lift in wage rates.

The more serious risk to inflation is if high actual inflation feeds into higher expected inflation. To date, short-term measures of expected inflation have moved in synch with the pick-up in actual inflation. However, the Fed’s index of inflation expectations, which gives a larger weight to long-term measures of inflation expectations and is the series we used in the simple model of inflation above, is still close the Fed’s 2% inflation target. 

The 1970s showed how long-term inflation expectations can become unmoored, entrenching extremely high inflation, although that happened over several years, driven by persistently loose policy and two oil price shocks. If there were signs that long-term expectations were trending higher, that would automatically trigger an aggressive interest rate response from the Fed.

In a central forecast scenario, the Fed would raise the policy rate to a neutral level as inflation subsides later this year when pandemic disruptions moderate. 

However, there is a clear risk that inflation stays high for longer than anticipated for the reasons outlined above.  In such an upside scenario, the Fed would adopt tight monetary policy, leading to a risk of eventual recession. 

If that scenario were realised, analysis suggests that the most robust way to assess the risk of recession is to rely on the slope of the yield curve, albeit where the results are enhanced by adding the level of the Federal funds rate, such that an inverted yield curve matters more if it occurs at a higher level of interest rates. 

The yield curve does not always give strong signals of recession, but beats stock prices, which are its nearest competitor, where equities overpredict the occurrence of recessions. 

Estimating a simple model of the risk of recession in a year’s time based on the slope of the yield curve and the level of the funds rate, the model suggests that the risk is currently very low at about 5%. 

This is not surprising as the market is only factoring in a return to a broadly neutral level of the cash rate. As the Fed raises rates, the model’s estimated odds will increase. If short-term rates rise high enough and the yield curve inverts, model odds of 30‑40% have been associated with the past four recessions. 

Although the yield curve has the best track record of any economic or financial indicator in signalling the risk of recession, there is the possibility that unconventional monetary policy is distorting the signal at the margin. This is because the Fed’s enormous quantitative easing (QE) programme has reduced bond yields and quantitative tightening (QT) will work in reverse. Depending on the size and scale of QT as the Fed raises interest rates, this will reduce the model’s recession estimates at the margin.


........
Investment Disclaimer Past performance does not assure future returns. All investments carry risks, including that the value of investments may vary, future returns may differ from past returns, and that your capital is not guaranteed. This information has been prepared by Coolabah Capital Investments Pty Ltd (ACN 153 327 872). It is general information only and is not intended to provide you with financial advice. You should not rely on any information herein in making any investment decisions. To the extent permitted by law, no liability is accepted for any loss or damage as a result of any reliance on this information. The Product Disclosure Statement (PDS) for the funds should be considered before deciding whether to acquire or hold units in it. A PDS for these products can be obtained by visiting www.coolabahcapital.com. Neither Coolabah Capital Investments Pty Ltd, Equity Trustees Ltd (ACN 004 031 298) nor their respective shareholders, directors and associated businesses assume any liability to investors in connection with any investment in the funds, or guarantees the performance of any obligations to investors, the performance of the funds or any particular rate of return. The repayment of capital is not guaranteed. Investments in the funds are not deposits or liabilities of any of the above-mentioned parties, nor of any Authorised Deposit-taking Institution. The funds are subject to investment risks, which could include delays in repayment and/or loss of income and capital invested. Past performance is not an indicator of nor assures any future returns or risks. Coolabah Capital Investments (Retail) Pty Limited (CCIR) (ACN 153 555 867) is an authorised representative (#000414337) of Coolabah Capital Institutional Investments Pty Ltd (CCII) (AFSL 482238). Both CCIR and CCII are wholly owned subsidiaries of Coolabah Capital Investments Pty Ltd. Equity Trustees Ltd (AFSL 240975) is the Responsible Entity for these funds. Equity Trustees Ltd is a subsidiary of EQT Holdings Limited (ACN 607 797 615), a publicly listed company on the Australian Securities Exchange (ASX: EQT). Forward-Looking Disclaimer This presentation contains some forward-looking information. These statements are not guarantees of future performance and undue reliance should not be placed on them. Such forward-looking statements necessarily involve known and unknown risks and uncertainties, which may cause actual performance and financial results in future periods to differ materially from any projections of future performance or result expressed or implied by such forward-looking statements. Although forward-looking statements contained in this presentation are based upon what Coolabah Capital Investments Pty Ltd believes are reasonable assumptions, there can be no assurance that forward-looking statements will prove to be accurate, as actual results and future events could differ materially from those anticipated in such statements. Coolabah Capital Investments Pty Ltd undertakes no obligation to update forward-looking statements if circumstances or management’s estimates or opinions should change except as required by applicable securities laws. The reader is cautioned not to place undue reliance on forward-looking statements.

Kieran Davies
Chief Macro Strategist
Coolabah Capital

Based in Sydney, Kieran Davies is Chief Macro Strategist at Coolabah Capital Investments, an asset manager with 40 executives and over $8 billion in fixed-income strategies. Kieran is responsible for macroeconomic research and investment strategy,...

I would like to

Only to be used for sending genuine email enquiries to the Contributor. Livewire Markets Pty Ltd reserves its right to take any legal or other appropriate action in relation to misuse of this service.

Personal Information Collection Statement
Your personal information will be passed to the Contributor and/or its authorised service provider to assist the Contributor to contact you about your investment enquiry. They are required not to use your information for any other purpose. Our privacy policy explains how we store personal information and how you may access, correct or complain about the handling of personal information.

Comments

Sign In or Join Free to comment